Robert Samuelson December 22, 2013

December 23, 2013
By Robert Samuelson

December 22, 2013
 


The Fed turns 100 Monday. A century ago — on Dec. 23, 1913President Woodrow Wilson signed legislation establishing the Federal Reserve. Broadly speaking, it was charged with preventing financial crises andpreserving prosperity. The record is mixed. Despite many successfulyears (the 1920s, 1940s, 1950s, 1980s and 1990s), the Fed’s performanceis marred by three huge blunders: the Great Depression of the 1930s, the Great Inflation of the late 1960s and 1970s and the 2008-09 financialcrisis. Had the Fed acted differently in each case, the outcome wouldhave been different and better.

There’s a disheartening consistency to the Fed’s cycles of successand failure. The beliefs and policies of one era aren’t suitable to theconditions and challenges of the next, but the Fed adapts only slowlyunder the press of events.

Created after the Panic of 1907, theFed first focused on averting bank runs. At the time, loan demand andinterest rates were highly seasonal; they rose in the spring and thefall, reflecting the credit needs of planting and harvesting crops. Anynasty surprise (bad harvests, business failures, stock market losses)risked a run, as depositors feared that strapped banks couldn’t returntheir money. After all, most of it had been lent out. Unlike today,deposit insurance didn’t exist.

The Fed solved this problem, says Harvard economist Jeffrey Miron. Money became more “elastic.” When credit demand was high, the Fed lentmore. Seasonal interest-rate swings subsided. Confidence grew becausedepositors knew that, in a panic, banks could borrow from the Fed tomeet currency demands. In the 1920s, there were no major bank runs.

But what succeeded in the 1920s backfired in the 1930s. Faced with acollapsing economy, “the Federal Reserve did next to nothing to fosterrecovery,” writes economist Allan Meltzer in his exhaustive history of the Fed. It was passive, because — based on its 1920s experience — weak loandemand signaled that there was little for the Fed to do. Credit seemedeasy; loanable funds seemed ample.

This was a fatal error. Weakloan demand mainly reflected the economy’s devastated state. To promoterevival, the Fed needed to pump money aggressively into the financialsystem. It didn’t. From 1929 to 1932, real gross domestic product (GDP)fell 25 percent. (For comparison, GDP’s drop in the recent Great Recession was 4.3 percent.) In 1932, the unemployment rate was 23 percent. Many, probably most,economists think a lax Fed converted an ordinary slump into theDepression.

By contrast, the mistake of the 1960s and 1970s wasjust the opposite: not passivity, but activism. The 1930s lesson — “domore” — was learned too well. The Fed assumed that shifts in interestrates could keep the economy near “full employment,” defined as 4percent unemployment. In practice, the commitment to full employment,also embraced by successive presidents beginning with John Kennedy,unleashed inflationary expectations (why restrain wages and prices ifgovernment guarantees prosperity?) and easy credit. By the late 1970s, inflation was spiraling out of control at 13 percent.

Subduing it was a triumph of economic policy. After Paul Volcker, Fed chairmanfrom 1979 to 1987, accomplished this with a brutal recession (unemployment reached 10.8 percent) in the early 1980s, the lesson seemed self-evident: Keep inflation lowand stable. The uncertainties of volatile prices would fade. Steadygrowth and prosperity would follow. So it seemed. From 1982 to 2007,there were only two mild recessions. The Fed, mostly under AlanGreenspan, seemed omnipotent. It controlled inflation and repulsedthreats to economic growth: the 1987 stock crash, the Asian financialcrisis and the Sept. 11, 2001, attacks.

Unfortunately, thissuccess abetted the 2008-09 financial crisis. Prolonged prosperityseemed to reduce risks; investors could rationalize taking more risks,because the downside seemed limited. Sloppy, dangerous and unethicalpractices spread at banks and other financial institutions. Meanwhile, low inflation reassured the Fed. It distracted attention from the financial system, whose overallstability, in any case, didn’t worry most officials. An Americanfinancial collapse hadn’t happened since World War II and was anunthinkable abstraction, outside their personal experience. The resultwas that “we were slow to recognize the crisis,” as retiring FedChairman Ben Bernanke said recently.

What’s clear is that the Fed isn’t as powerful as it seemed under Greenspan.True, once Bernanke acknowledged the crisis, he acted forcefully to pump funds into the financial system. For this, he has been widely anddeservedly praised. A second Great Depression was possibly avoided; the1930s failure was not repeated. But the Fed has discovered that it lacks the power to resuscitate the economy single-handedly. Five years ofshort-term interest rates near zero and roughly $3 trillion ofbond-buying have, at most, modestly improved a weak recovery. On itscentennial, one word best describes the Fed: frustration.